Appeals Court Ruling: United States v. Microsoft Corp.
Thursday, June 28, 2001
I. Introduction
A. Background
In July 1994, officials at the Department of Justice
("DOJ"), on behalf of the United States, filed suit against
Microsoft, charging the company with, among other things,
unlawfully maintaining a monopoly in the operating system
market through anticompetitive terms in its licensing and
software developer agreements. The parties subsequently
entered into a consent decree, thus avoiding a trial on the
merits. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 F.3d 1448
(D.C. Cir. 1995) ("Microsoft I"). Three years later, the
Justice Department filed a civil contempt action against Mi-
crosoft for allegedly violating one of the decree's provisions.
On appeal from a grant of a preliminary injunction, this court
held that Microsoft's technological bundling of IE 3.0 and 4.0
with Windows 95 did not violate the relevant provision of the
consent decree. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 147 F.3d
935 (D.C. Cir. 1998) ("Microsoft II"). We expressly reserved
the question whether such bundling might independently
violate ss 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act. Id. at 950 n.14.
On May 18, 1998, shortly before issuance of the Microsoft
II decision, the United States and a group of State plaintiffs
filed separate (and soon thereafter consolidated) complaints,
asserting antitrust violations by Microsoft and seeking pre-
liminary and permanent injunctions against the company's
allegedly unlawful conduct. The complaints also sought any
"other preliminary and permanent relief as is necessary and
appropriate to restore competitive conditions in the markets
affected by Microsoft's unlawful conduct." Gov't's Compl. at
53, United States v. Microsoft Corp., No. 98-1232 (D.D.C.
1999). Relying almost exclusively on Microsoft's varied ef-
forts to unseat Netscape Navigator as the preeminent inter-
net browser, plaintiffs charged four distinct violations of the
Sherman Act: (1) unlawful exclusive dealing arrangements in
violation of s 1; (2) unlawful tying of IE to Windows 95 and
Windows 98 in violation of s 1; (3) unlawful maintenance of a
monopoly in the PC operating system market in violation of
s 2; and (4) unlawful attempted monopolization of the inter-
net browser market in violation of s 2. The States also
brought pendent claims charging Microsoft with violations of
various State antitrust laws.
The District Court scheduled the case on a "fast track."
The hearing on the preliminary injunction and the trial on the
merits were consolidated pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 65(a)(2).
The trial was then scheduled to commence on September 8,
1998, less than four months after the complaints had been
filed. In a series of pretrial orders, the District Court limited
each side to a maximum of 12 trial witnesses plus two
rebuttal witnesses. It required that all trial witnesses' direct
testimony be submitted to the court in the form of written
declarations. The District Court also made allowances for
the use of deposition testimony at trial to prove subordinate
or predicate issues. Following the grant of three brief con-
tinuances, the trial started on October 19, 1998.
After a 76-day bench trial, the District Court issued its
Findings of Fact. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 84
F. Supp. 2d 9 (D.D.C. 1999) ("Findings of Fact"). This
triggered two independent courses of action. First, the Dis-
trict Court established a schedule for briefing on possible
legal conclusions, inviting Professor Lawrence Lessig to par-
ticipate as amicus curiae. Second, the District Court re-
ferred the case to mediation to afford the parties an opportu-
nity to settle their differences. The Honorable Richard A.
Posner, Chief Judge of the United States Court of Appeals
for the Seventh Circuit, was appointed to serve as mediator.
The parties concurred in the referral to mediation and in the
choice of mediator.
Mediation failed after nearly four months of settlement
talks between the parties. On April 3, 2000, with the parties'
briefs having been submitted and considered, the District
Court issued its conclusions of law. The District Court found
Microsoft liable on the s 1 tying and s 2 monopoly mainte-
nance and attempted monopolization claims, Conclusions of
Law, at 35-51, while ruling that there was insufficient evi-
dence to support a s 1 exclusive dealing violation, id. at 51-
54. As to the pendent State actions, the District Court found
the State antitrust laws conterminous with ss 1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act, thereby obviating the need for further State-
specific analysis. Id. at 54-56. In those few cases where a
State's law required an additional showing of intrastate im-
pact on competition, the District Court found the requirement
easily satisfied on the evidence at hand. Id. at 55.
Having found Microsoft liable on all but one count, the
District Court then asked plaintiffs to submit a proposed
remedy. Plaintiffs' proposal for a remedial order was subse-
quently filed within four weeks, along with six supplemental
declarations and over 50 new exhibits. In their proposal,
plaintiffs sought specific conduct remedies, plus structural
relief that would split Microsoft into an applications company
and an operating systems company. The District Court
rejected Microsoft's request for further evidentiary proceed-
ings and, following a single hearing on the merits of the
remedy question, issued its Final Judgment on June 7, 2000.
The District Court adopted plaintiffs' proposed remedy with-
out substantive change.
Microsoft filed a notice of appeal within a week after the
District Court issued its Final Judgment. This court then
ordered that any proceedings before it be heard by the court
sitting en banc. Before any substantive matters were ad-
dressed by this court, however, the District Court certified
appeal of the case brought by the United States directly to
the Supreme Court pursuant to 15 U.S.C. s 29(b), while
staying the final judgment order in the federal and state
cases pending appeal. The States thereafter petitioned the
Supreme Court for a writ of certiorari in their case. The
Supreme Court declined to hear the appeal of the Govern-
ment's case and remanded the matter to this court; the Court
likewise denied the States' petition for writ of certiorari.
Microsoft Corp. v. United States, 530 U.S. 1301 (2000). This
consolidated appeal followed.
B. Overview
Before turning to the merits of Microsoft's various argu-
ments, we pause to reflect briefly on two matters of note, one
practical and one theoretical.
The practical matter relates to the temporal dimension of
this case. The litigation timeline in this case is hardly
problematic. Indeed, it is noteworthy that a case of this
magnitude and complexity has proceeded from the filing of
complaints through trial to appellate decision in a mere three
years. See, e.g., Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support
Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1155 (1st Cir. 1994) (six years from filing
of complaint to appellate decision); Transamerica Computer
Co., Inc. v. IBM, 698 F.2d 1377, 1381 (9th Cir. 1983) (over
four years from start of trial to appellate decision); United
States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295, 298 (D.
Mass. 1953) (over five years from filing of complaint to trial
court decision).
What is somewhat problematic, however, is that just over
six years have passed since Microsoft engaged in the first
conduct plaintiffs allege to be anticompetitive. As the record
in this case indicates, six years seems like an eternity in the
computer industry. By the time a court can assess liability,
firms, products, and the marketplace are likely to have
changed dramatically. This, in turn, threatens enormous
practical difficulties for courts considering the appropriate
measure of relief in equitable enforcement actions, both in
crafting injunctive remedies in the first instance and review-
ing those remedies in the second. Conduct remedies may be
unavailing in such cases, because innovation to a large degree
has already rendered the anticompetitive conduct obsolete
(although by no means harmless). And broader structural
remedies present their own set of problems, including how a
court goes about restoring competition to a dramatically
changed, and constantly changing, marketplace. That is just
one reason why we find the District Court's refusal in the
present case to hold an evidentiary hearing on remedies--to
update and flesh out the available information before serious-
ly entertaining the possibility of dramatic structural relief--so
problematic. See infra Section V.
We do not mean to say that enforcement actions will no
longer play an important role in curbing infringements of the
antitrust laws in technologically dynamic markets, nor do we
assume this in assessing the merits of this case. Even in
those cases where forward-looking remedies appear limited,
the Government will continue to have an interest in defining
the contours of the antitrust laws so that law-abiding firms
will have a clear sense of what is permissible and what is not.
And the threat of private damage actions will remain to deter
those firms inclined to test the limits of the law.
The second matter of note is more theoretical in nature.
We decide this case against a backdrop of significant debate
amongst academics and practitioners over the extent to
which "old economy" s 2 monopolization doctrines should
apply to firms competing in dynamic technological markets
characterized by network effects. In markets characterized
by network effects, one product or standard tends towards
dominance, because "the utility that a user derives from con-
sumption of the good increases with the number of other
agents consuming the good." Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapi-
ro, Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility,
75 Am. Econ. Rev. 424, 424 (1985). For example, "[a]n
individual consumer's demand to use (and hence her benefit
from) the telephone network ... increases with the number
of other users on the network whom she can call or from
whom she can receive calls." Howard A. Shelanski & J.
Gregory Sidak, Antitrust Divestiture in Network Industries,
68 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1, 8 (2001). Once a product or standard
achieves wide acceptance, it becomes more or less en-
trenched. Competition in such industries is "for the field"
rather than "within the field." See Harold Demsetz, Why
Regulate Utilities?, 11 J.L. & Econ. 55, 57 & n.7 (1968)
(emphasis omitted).
In technologically dynamic markets, however, such en-
trenchment may be temporary, because innovation may alter
the field altogether. See Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy 81-90 (Harper Perennial 1976)
(1942). Rapid technological change leads to markets in which
"firms compete through innovation for temporary market
dominance, from which they may be displaced by the next
wave of product advancements." Shelanski & Sidak, at 11-12
(discussing Schumpeterian competition, which proceeds "se-
quentially over time rather than simultaneously across a
market"). Microsoft argues that the operating system mar-
ket is just such a market.
Whether or not Microsoft's characterization of the operat-
ing system market is correct does not appreciably alter our
mission in assessing the alleged antitrust violations in the
present case. As an initial matter, we note that there is no
consensus among commentators on the question of whether,
and to what extent, current monopolization doctrine should be
amended to account for competition in technologically dynam-
ic markets characterized by network effects. Compare Ste-
ven C. Salop & R. Craig Romaine, Preserving Monopoly:
Economic Analysis, Legal Standards, and Microsoft, 7 Geo.
Mason L. Rev. 617, 654-55, 663-64 (1999) (arguing that
exclusionary conduct in high-tech networked industries de-
serves heightened antitrust scrutiny in part because it may
threaten to deter innovation), with Ronald A. Cass & Keith
N. Hylton, Preserving Competition: Economic Analysis, Le-
gal Standards and Microsoft, 8 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 1, 36-39
(1999) (equivocating on the antitrust implications of network
effects and noting that the presence of network externalities
may actually encourage innovation by guaranteeing more
durable monopolies to innovating winners). Indeed, there is
some suggestion that the economic consequences of network
effects and technological dynamism act to offset one another,
thereby making it difficult to formulate categorical antitrust
rules absent a particularized analysis of a given market. See
Shelanski & Sidak, at 6-7 ("High profit margins might appear
to be the benign and necessary recovery of legitimate invest-
ment returns in a Schumpeterian framework, but they might
represent exploitation of customer lock-in and monopoly pow-
er when viewed through the lens of network economics....
The issue is particularly complex because, in network indus-
tries characterized by rapid innovation, both forces may be
operating and can be difficult to isolate.").
Moreover, it should be clear that Microsoft makes no claim
that anticompetitive conduct should be assessed differently in
technologically dynamic markets. It claims only that the
measure of monopoly power should be different. For reasons
fully discussed below, we reject Microsoft's monopoly power
argument. See infra Section II.A.
With this backdrop in mind, we turn to the specific chal-
lenges raised in Microsoft's appeal.
II. Monopolization
Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes it unlawful for a firm
to "monopolize." 15 U.S.C. s 2. The offense of monopoliza-
tion has two elements: "(1) the possession of monopoly power
in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or
maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or
development as a consequence of a superior product, business
acumen, or historic accident." United States v. Grinnell
Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966). The District Court ap-
plied this test and found that Microsoft possesses monopoly
power in the market for Intel-compatible PC operating sys-
tems. Focusing primarily on Microsoft's efforts to suppress
Netscape Navigator's threat to its operating system monopo-
ly, the court also found that Microsoft maintained its power
not through competition on the merits, but through unlawful
means. Microsoft challenges both conclusions. We defer to
the District Court's findings of fact, setting them aside only if
clearly erroneous. Fed R. Civ. P. 52(a). We review legal
questions de novo. United States ex rel. Modern Elec., Inc.
v. Ideal Elec. Sec. Co., 81 F.3d 240, 244 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
We begin by considering whether Microsoft possesses mo-
nopoly power, see infra Section II.A, and finding that it does,
we turn to the question whether it maintained this power
through anticompetitive means. Agreeing with the District
Court that the company behaved anticompetitively, see infra
Section II.B, and that these actions contributed to the mainte-
nance of its monopoly power, see infra Section II.C, we affirm
the court's finding of liability for monopolization.
A. Monopoly Power
While merely possessing monopoly power is not itself an
antitrust violation, see Northeastern Tel. Co. v. AT & T, 651
F.2d 76, 84-85 (2d Cir. 1981), it is a necessary element of a
monopolization charge, see Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 570. The
Supreme Court defines monopoly power as "the power to
control prices or exclude competition." United States v. E.I.
du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956). More
precisely, a firm is a monopolist if it can profitably raise
prices substantially above the competitive level. 2A Phillip
E. Areeda et al., Antitrust Law p 501, at 85 (1995); cf. Ball
Mem'l Hosp., Inc. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins., Inc., 784 F.2d 1325,
1335 (7th Cir. 1986) (defining market power as "the ability to
cut back the market's total output and so raise price").
Where evidence indicates that a firm has in fact profitably
done so, the existence of monopoly power is clear. See Rebel
Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir.
1995); see also FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S.
447, 460-61 (1986) (using direct proof to show market power
in Sherman Act s 1 unreasonable restraint of trade action).
Because such direct proof is only rarely available, courts
more typically examine market structure in search of circum-
stantial evidence of monopoly power. 2A Areeda et al.,
Antitrust Law p 531a, at 156; see also, e.g., Grinnell, 384 U.S.
at 571. Under this structural approach, monopoly power may
be inferred from a firm's possession of a dominant share of a
relevant market that is protected by entry barriers. See
Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1434. "Entry barriers" are factors
(such as certain regulatory requirements) that prevent new
rivals from timely responding to an increase in price above
the competitive level. See S. Pac. Communications Co. v.
AT & T, 740 F.2d 980, 1001-02 (D.C. Cir. 1984).
The District Court considered these structural factors and
concluded that Microsoft possesses monopoly power in a
relevant market. Defining the market as Intel-compatible
PC operating systems, the District Court found that Micro-
soft has a greater than 95% share. It also found the compa-
ny's market position protected by a substantial entry barrier.
Conclusions of Law, at 36.
Microsoft argues that the District Court incorrectly defined
the relevant market. It also claims that there is no barrier to
entry in that market. Alternatively, Microsoft argues that
because the software industry is uniquely dynamic, direct
proof, rather than circumstantial evidence, more appropriate-
ly indicates whether it possesses monopoly power. Rejecting
each argument, we uphold the District Court's finding of
monopoly power in its entirety.
1. Market Structure
a. Market definition
"Because the ability of consumers to turn to other suppliers
restrains a firm from raising prices above the competitive
level," Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc.,
792 F.2d 210, 218 (D.C. Cir. 1986), the relevant market must
include all products "reasonably interchangeable by consum-
ers for the same purposes." du Pont, 351 U.S. at 395. In
this case, the District Court defined the market as "the
licensing of all Intel-compatible PC operating systems world-
wide," finding that there are "currently no products--and ...
there are not likely to be any in the near future--that a
significant percentage of computer users worldwide could
substitute for [these operating systems] without incurring
substantial costs." Conclusions of Law, at 36. Calling this
market definition "far too narrow," Appellant's Opening Br.
at 84, Microsoft argues that the District Court improperly
excluded three types of products: non-Intel compatible oper-
ating systems (primarily Apple's Macintosh operating system,
Mac OS), operating systems for non-PC devices (such as
handheld computers and portal websites), and "middleware"
products, which are not operating systems at all.
We begin with Mac OS. Microsoft's argument that Mac
OS should have been included in the relevant market suffers
from a flaw that infects many of the company's monopoly
power claims: the company fails to challenge the District
Court's factual findings, or to argue that these findings do not
support the court's conclusions. The District Court found
that consumers would not switch from Windows to Mac OS in
response to a substantial price increase because of the costs
of acquiring the new hardware needed to run Mac OS (an
Apple computer and peripherals) and compatible software
applications, as well as because of the effort involved in
learning the new system and transferring files to its format.
Findings of Fact p 20. The court also found the Apple
system less appealing to consumers because it costs consider-
ably more and supports fewer applications. Id. p 21. Micro-
soft responds only by saying: "the district court's market
definition is so narrow that it excludes Apple's Mac OS, which
has competed with Windows for years, simply because the
Mac OS runs on a different microprocessor." Appellant's
Opening Br. at 84. This general, conclusory statement falls
far short of what is required to challenge findings as clearly
erroneous. Pendleton v. Rumsfeld, 628 F.2d 102, 106 (D.C.
Cir. 1980); see also Terry v. Reno, 101 F.3d 1412, 1415 (D.C.
Cir. 1996) (holding that claims made but not argued in a brief
are waived). Microsoft neither points to evidence contradict-
ing the District Court's findings nor alleges that supporting
record evidence is insufficient. And since Microsoft does not
argue that even if we accept these findings, they do not
support the District Court's conclusion, we have no basis for
upsetting the court's decision to exclude Mac OS from the
relevant market.
Microsoft's challenge to the District Court's exclusion of
non-PC based competitors, such as information appliances
(handheld devices, etc.) and portal websites that host server-
based software applications, suffers from the same defect:
the company fails to challenge the District Court's key factual
findings. In particular, the District Court found that because
information appliances fall far short of performing all of the
functions of a PC, most consumers will buy them only as a
supplement to their PCs. Findings of Fact p 23. The Dis-
trict Court also found that portal websites do not presently
host enough applications to induce consumers to switch, nor
are they likely to do so in the near future. Id. p 27. Again,
because Microsoft does not argue that the District Court's
findings do not support its conclusion that information appli-
ances and portal websites are outside the relevant market, we
adhere to that conclusion.
This brings us to Microsoft's main challenge to the District
Court's market definition: the exclusion of middleware. Be-
cause of the importance of middleware to this case, we pause
to explain what it is and how it relates to the issue before us.
Operating systems perform many functions, including allo-
cating computer memory and controlling peripherals such as
printers and keyboards. See Direct Testimony of Frederick
Warren-Boulton p 20, reprinted in 5 J.A. at 3172-73. Oper-
ating systems also function as platforms for software applica-
tions. They do this by "exposing"--i.e., making available to
software developers--routines or protocols that perform cer-
tain widely-used functions. These are known as Application
Programming Interfaces, or "APIs." See Direct Testimony
of James Barksdale p 70, reprinted in 5 J.A. at 2895-96. For
example, Windows contains an API that enables users to
draw a box on the screen. See Direct Testimony of Michael
T. Devlin p 12, reprinted in 5 J.A. at 3525. Software develop-
ers wishing to include that function in an application need not
duplicate it in their own code. Instead, they can "call"--i.e.,
use--the Windows API. See Direct Testimony of James
Barksdale p p 70-71, reprinted in 5 J.A. at 2895-97. Win-
dows contains thousands of APIs, controlling everything from
data storage to font display. See Direct Testimony of Mi-
chael Devlin p 12, reprinted in 5 J.A. at 3525.
Every operating system has different APIs. Accordingly,
a developer who writes an application for one operating
system and wishes to sell the application to users of another
must modify, or "port," the application to the second operat-
ing system. Findings of Fact p 4. This process is both time-
consuming and expensive. Id. p 30.
"Middleware" refers to software products that expose their
own APIs. Id. p 28; Direct Testimony of Paul Maritz
p p 234-36, reprinted in 6 J.A. at 3727-29. Because of this, a
middleware product written for Windows could take over
some or all of Windows's valuable platform functions--that is,
developers might begin to rely upon APIs exposed by the
middleware for basic routines rather than relying upon the
API set included in Windows. If middleware were written
for multiple operating systems, its impact could be even
greater. The more developers could rely upon APIs exposed
by such middleware, the less expensive porting to different
operating systems would be. Ultimately, if developers could
write applications relying exclusively on APIs exposed by
middleware, their applications would run on any operating
system on which the middleware was also present. See
Direct Testimony of Avadis Tevanian, Jr. p 45, reprinted in 5
J.A. at 3113. Netscape Navigator and Java--both at issue in
this case--are middleware products written for multiple oper-
ating systems. Findings of Fact p 28.
Microsoft argues that, because middleware could usurp the
operating system's platform function and might eventually
take over other operating system functions (for instance, by
controlling peripherals), the District Court erred in excluding
Navigator and Java from the relevant market. The District
Court found, however, that neither Navigator, Java, nor any
other middleware product could now, or would soon, expose
enough APIs to serve as a platform for popular applications,
much less take over all operating system functions. Id.
p p 28-29. Again, Microsoft fails to challenge these findings,
instead simply asserting middleware's "potential" as a com-
petitor. Appellant's Opening Br. at 86. The test of reason-
able interchangeability, however, required the District Court
to consider only substitutes that constrain pricing in the
reasonably foreseeable future, and only products that can
enter the market in a relatively short time can perform this
function. See Rothery, 792 F.2d at 218 ("Because the ability
of consumers to turn to other suppliers restrains a firm from
raising prices above the competitive level, the definition of the
'relevant market' rests on a determination of available substi-
tutes."); see also Findings of Fact p 29 ("[I]t would take
several years for middleware ... to evolve" into a product
that can constrain operating system pricing.). Whatever
middleware's ultimate potential, the District Court found that
consumers could not now abandon their operating systems
and switch to middleware in response to a sustained price for
Windows above the competative level. Findings of Fact
p p 28, 29. Nor is middleware likely to overtake the operat-
ing system as the primary platform for software development
any time in the near future. Id.
Alternatively, Microsoft argues that the District Court
should not have excluded middleware from the relevant mar-
ket because the primary focus of the plaintiffs' s 2 charge is
on Microsoft's attempts to suppress middleware's threat to its
operating system monopoly. According to Microsoft, it is
"contradict[ory]," 2/26/2001 Ct. Appeals Tr. at 20, to define
the relevant market to exclude the "very competitive threats
that gave rise" to the action. Appellant's Opening Br. at 84.
The purported contradiction lies between plaintiffs' s 2 theo-
ry, under which Microsoft preserved its monopoly against
middleware technologies that threatened to become viable
substitutes for Windows, and its theory of the relevant mar-
ket, under which middleware is not presently a viable substi-
tute for Windows. Because middleware's threat is only nas-
cent, however, no contradiction exists. Nothing in s 2 of the
Sherman Act limits its prohibition to actions taken against
threats that are already well-developed enough to serve as
present substitutes. See infra Section II.C. Because market
definition is meant to identify products "reasonably inter-
changeable by consumers," du Pont, 351 U.S. at 395, and
because middleware is not now interchangeable with Win-
dows, the District Court had good reason for excluding
middleware from the relevant market.
b. Market power
Having thus properly defined the relevant market, the
District Court found that Windows accounts for a greater
than 95% share. Findings of Fact p 35. The court also
found that even if Mac OS were included, Microsoft's share
would exceed 80%. Id. Microsoft challenges neither finding,
nor does it argue that such a market share is not predomi-
nant. Cf. Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 571 (87% is predominant);
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S.
451, 481 (1992) (80%); du Pont, 351 U.S. at 379, 391 (75%).
Instead, Microsoft claims that even a predominant market
share does not by itself indicate monopoly power. Although
the "existence of [monopoly] power ordinarily may be in-
ferred from the predominant share of the market," Grinnell,
384 U.S. at 571, we agree with Microsoft that because of the
possibility of competition from new entrants, see Ball Mem'l
Hosp., Inc., 784 F.2d at 1336, looking to current market share
alone can be "misleading." Hunt-Wesson Foods, Inc. v.
Ragu Foods, Inc., 627 F.2d 919, 924 (9th Cir. 1980); see also
Ball Mem'l Hosp., Inc., 784 F.2d at 1336 ("Market share
reflects current sales, but today's sales do not always indicate
power over sales and price tomorrow.") In this case, howev-
er, the District Court was not misled. Considering the
possibility of new rivals, the court focused not only on Micro-
soft's present market share, but also on the structural barrier
that protects the company's future position. Conclusions of
Law, at 36. That barrier--the "applications barrier to en-
try"--stems from two characteristics of the software market:
(1) most consumers prefer operating systems for which a
large number of applications have already been written; and
(2) most developers prefer to write for operating systems that
already have a substantial consumer base. See Findings of
Fact p p 30, 36. This "chicken-and-egg" situation ensures
that applications will continue to be written for the already
dominant Windows, which in turn ensures that consumers will
continue to prefer it over other operating systems. Id.
Challenging the existence of the applications barrier to
entry, Microsoft observes that software developers do write
applications for other operating systems, pointing out that at
its peak IBM's OS/2 supported approximately 2,500 applica-
tions. Id. p 46. This misses the point. That some develop-
ers write applications for other operating systems is not at all
inconsistent with the finding that the applications barrier to
entry discourages many from writing for these less popular
platforms. Indeed, the District Court found that IBM's
difficulty in attracting a larger number of software developers
to write for its platform seriously impeded OS/2's success.
Id. p 46.
Microsoft does not dispute that Windows supports many
more applications than any other operating system. It ar-
gues instead that "[i]t defies common sense" to suggest that
an operating system must support as many applications as
Windows does (more than 70,000, according to the District
Court, id. p 40) to be competitive. Appellant's Opening Br. at
96. Consumers, Microsoft points out, can only use a very
small percentage of these applications. Id. As the District
Court explained, however, the applications barrier to entry
gives consumers reason to prefer the dominant operating
system even if they have no need to use all applications
written for it:
The consumer wants an operating system that runs not
only types of applications that he knows he will want to
use, but also those types in which he might develop an
interest later. Also, the consumer knows that if he
chooses an operating system with enough demand to
support multiple applications in each product category,
he will be less likely to find himself straitened later by
having to use an application whose features disappoint
him. Finally, the average user knows that, generally
speaking, applications improve through successive ver-
sions. He thus wants an operating system for which
successive generations of his favorite applications will be
released--promptly at that. The fact that a vastly larger
number of applications are written for Windows than for
other PC operating systems attracts consumers to Win-
dows, because it reassures them that their interests will
be met as long as they use Microsoft's product.
Findings of Fact p 37. Thus, despite the limited success of
its rivals, Microsoft benefits from the applications barrier to
entry.
Of course, were middleware to succeed, it would erode the
applications barrier to entry. Because applications written
for multiple operating systems could run on any operating
system on which the middleware product was present with
little, if any, porting, the operating system market would
become competitive. Id. p p 29, 72. But as the District Court
found, middleware will not expose a sufficient number of
APIs to erode the applications barrier to entry in the foresee-
able future. See id. p p 28-29.
Microsoft next argues that the applications barrier to entry
is not an entry barrier at all, but a reflection of Windows'
popularity. It is certainly true that Windows may have
gained its initial dominance in the operating system market
competitively--through superior foresight or quality. But
this case is not about Microsoft's initial acquisition of monopo-
ly power. It is about Microsoft's efforts to maintain this
position through means other than competition on the merits.
Because the applications barrier to entry protects a dominant
operating system irrespective of quality, it gives Microsoft
power to stave off even superior new rivals. The barrier is
thus a characteristic of the operating system market, not of
Microsoft's popularity, or, as asserted by a Microsoft witness,
the company's efficiency. See Direct Testimony of Richard
Schmalensee p 115, reprinted in 25 J.A. at 16153-14.
Finally, Microsoft argues that the District Court should not
have considered the applications barrier to entry because it
reflects not a cost borne disproportionately by new entrants,
but one borne by all participants in the operating system
market. According to Microsoft, it had to make major invest-
ments to convince software developers to write for its new
operating system, and it continues to "evangelize" the Win-
dows platform today. Whether costs borne by all market
participants should be considered entry barriers is the sub-
ject of much debate. Compare 2A Areeda & Hovenkamp,
Antitrust Law s 420c, at 61 (arguing that these costs are
entry barriers), and Joe S. Bain, Barriers to New Competi-
tion: Their Character and Consequences in Manufacturing
Industries 6-7 (1956) (considering these costs entry barriers),
with L.A. Land Co. v. Brunswick Corp., 6 F.3d 1422, 1428
(9th Cir. 1993) (evaluating cost based on "[t]he disadvantage
of new entrants as compared to incumbents"), and George
Stigler, The Organization of Industry 67 (1968) (excluding
these costs). We need not resolve this issue, however, for
even under the more narrow definition it is clear that there
are barriers. When Microsoft entered the operating system
market with MS-DOS and the first version of Windows, it did
not confront a dominant rival operating system with as mas-
sive an installed base and as vast an existing array of
applications as the Windows operating systems have since
enjoyed. Findings of Fact p p 6, 7, 43. Moreover, when
Microsoft introduced Windows 95 and 98, it was able to
bypass the applications barrier to entry that protected the
incumbent Windows by including APIs from the earlier ver-
sion in the new operating systems. See id. p 44. This made
porting existing Windows applications to the new version of
Windows much less costly than porting them to the operating
systems of other entrants who could not freely include APIs
from the incumbent Windows with their own.
Previous Page Back to the top Next Page
© 2001 The Washington Post Company
|